Discussion about this post

User's avatar
Doctor Hammer's avatar

While I agree with your overall argument, I think you will want to reevaluate your model of earlier, pre-capitalistic societies.

Starting with the notion that stealing is more efficient than producing, that is quite a claim, seemingly not recognizing that stealing entails repeated exposure to violence and risk above and beyond merely producing. Hence why such a small proportion of the population can make any kind of a living doing it, and that portion spends a lot of time creating a moral system that justifies their theft as proper. Societies with lower non-theft productivity tend to see more bent towards violence, as the opportunity costs are lower, but even then it is a small proportion.

However, when it comes to war in later but still pre-modern periods, your "herbivores" make up the majority of those in the army. One of the biggest advantages of grain producing farmers, for instance, is that once the crop is planted there really isn't anything much for them to do with it for a few months, and thus the summer is the campaign season. It wasn't only the lords and their immediate men at arms marching off, but the levy of peasants bulking out the force.

Expand full comment
forumposter123@protonmail.com's avatar

High costs to war create a different problem.

"War is so costly you should give into my demands, because not doing so will mean war."

Thus, the cost of war alone doesn't solve the problem of war.

During the Cuban Missile Crisis we nearly had nuclear war. It was much closer than most people think. Was the principle that Cuba couldn't decide what weapons could be on its soil worth that? But if Cuba could do that what else could the commies do?

I think the most interesting aspect is that war "clarifies". Any amount of bullshit can go on being bullshit until some external objective force tests it. In capitalism that's profit/loss in the marketplace. Between states it can be war.

Expand full comment
37 more comments...

No posts